Ed Phillips on Fri, 13 Jan 2012 01:44:27 +0100 (CET) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
Re: <nettime> A Movement Without Demands? |
ïI'm sitting here reading yet another interesting thread on nettime, reflecting on the fact that this little watercooler on the nets is a more enduring institution than many large ones of Internet era discourse and finance. We can all print money as Minsky says, but to find a place where freshly minted thoughts or coins are accepted and used is something. I am thankful for that. Part of the appeal of this list to me is that we can discuss what Keith calls the banal. I find it helpful to rehearse what we "already know" so that some shared understanding starts to emerge. And one person's banality may be another's new way of thinking as well, or new twist on an old story. I found Jodie's and snafu's discussion of demands to be very helpful, for example. In an earlier thread, in a conversation with Keith, we started to discuss the relations between profit, interest, and rent in the capitalist system. On that note, I found an interesting remark from Claudio Napoleoni in 1970 in which he states that in an advanced money economy under so-called Keynesian conditions "interest cannot be regarded as a reward which is necessary to the production process. Interest instead takes on the nature of a rent, which is how Keynes in fact saw it. Thus, the characteristic capitalistic income is reduced in status to an income typifying a pre-capitalistic economy." It does not fit capitalism's self image to be seen as an old pensioner living off of interest, nor a parasite collecting rent by squatting on the commons. Propping up the image of the capitalist as great risk taker, as heroic entrepreneur, or even as smart investor in production seems vital to the system itself. It increasingly looks more and more a farce. Farced up, stuffed, propped up. And we arrive at demoralization the more obviously the system is propped up and the more that losses are openly socialized. A moral lassitude is evident that is as damaging as any devaluation, or perhaps more damaging, in that it gives the lie to the system itself. Not only the self-validation of the system but also the motivation of groups and individuals within it is at stake if the only reasonable, viable option for return is rent seeking or tax farming. Discussions of interest, rent seeking, and tax farming are particularly relevant during this time of a structural crisis in capitalist finance. During times of extreme uncertainty, financiers will tend to hold a premium on liquidity and on the preservation of capital, which is exactly what the steersmen do not want or need. In the parlance of finance such a flight to safety is what is termed pro-cyclical. In other words, and this is laid out by Keynes and others, the very uncertainty of crisis conditions exacerbates the crisis. As Minsky said investors or capitalists if they are to invest or use their capital, will use or will seek some kind of protection from uncertainty or market forces. In other words, and especially during times of uncertainty, investors will seek safe haven returns in protected spheres. And if interest has been brought to zero in an effort to prop up asset prices and to forestall devaluation, then rent-seeking and tax farming become even more vital to survival even as they are more obviously alienating and demoralizing. They obviously not capitalist, or not a pretty or heroic version of capitalism. Chief amongst the rent-seekers and demoralizers, the center of the moral lassitude, and of the farce, are the big banks, the very large banking entities that are deemed systemically important enough to receive subsidy and lender of last resort support. These very large banking enterprises can be and are described as rent seekers who use the implicit guarantee of the policymakers to validate and support their worth, even if they are technically insolvent. They also give the lie to idea that somehow capitalism in aggregate promotes efficiency or efficient markets, as inefficiency is purposefully promoted in order to forestall devaluation and insolvency in the center of the financial system. The big banks are the other side of the coin of the public markets; they sell volatility insurance and underwrite the insurance of capital markets, and then they get bailed out when they cannot pay on the insurance (Taleb). Rent-seeking emerges here at its purest and as it becomes clearer in form, it becomes even more demoralizing. Paul Sweezy, of kinked demand curve fame, was looking at a similar world in the late 30's when he first started writing about monopoly capitalism and monopoly rent and about the ensuing stagnation of bureaucratic big business capitalism. Kenneth Burke wrote in 1937 that monopoly capitalism had given up the lie and that the then current socialization of losses had already created a situation in which the "casuistic stretching" necessary to validate capitalism to itself had already reached the level of untenable farce and that a new collectivist era may be in the offing. The following great war and subsequent hegemony of a Washington consensus capitalism actively promoted a myth of a kind of heroic capitalism that was already in the rear view mirror. It was able to keep growing and to route around chaos in ways that are now history. And here we are in another great demoralization, up against even greater limits for capitalism itself. And tax-farming looks like a last great business model. Except for the fact that government spending has also reached limits to its growth. Oops. At any such time as any system cannot validate itself on its own terms, it should have need of either "casuistic stretching" (Burke's term) in the best case or outright obfuscation or magical, self -immolating action in the worst case. One can look at the actions of the "system" in response to the crisis and see an opacity, innate inefficiency, and fetishism that would rival any parody of a cargo cult. Policy and booster response to the crisis looks like revivalist ritual, ineffectual and demoralizing. We all of us share in the reality of the crisis, although many will suffer much more severely than others the effects of the crisis and the effects of efforts to maintain the status quo. It may seem bizarre to honest observers that capitalism, which has been lurching from crisis to crisis and by some views has ever been in continual crisis, could have ever produced a congratulatory self commentary that purported to have escaped the business cycle and to have produced a kind of great moderation in which technocrats could use monetary and fiscal means to produce "soft landings". In the risk of sounding banal, as Keith Hart says, that view has been completely discredited. It is hard to measure and I suspect that it's hard to underestimate the shattering effect of uncertainty on the previously complacent. Every person, whatever the status, has felt the effects of this crisis and that is surely one of the starting points for commonality. If we take it as a given that commentary and discussion both about the implications of the crisis and about what current conditions of contemporary capitalism are will be extremely distorted and will at all costs avoid any discussion of the difficulties or contradictions that are evident, then we will have to look at the edges of discourse, at the lacuna, at the places of denial in mainstream and official discourse. For example, in the interview with Steve Keen that was posted to nettime, the interviewer brought up the subject of moral hazard. However, the subject of moral hazard was only brought up in discussion of the effect of a debt jubilee on borrowers. No mention was made of the fact that the whole discussion of moral hazard has arisen out of a history in which the most damage has been created by continual bailing out of banks and investors in the saddling of loss on the public. It is, in this historical context, obscenely obfuscating to use the language of moral hazard to talk about the potential effects of socializing the losses of individuals and not of of the financial system and its representative zombie banks. We can see the same kind of obfuscation in the fear that individual borrowers will create a condition of moral hazard if their loans or debts that they cannot repay are forgiven. One excellent quote from Steve Keen in the interview was the statement that, "any debt that cannot be repaid will not be repaid". Another point of commonality can be and is the precarity of labor. In the developed world the credit bubble masked many of the problems attendant to the precarious state of labor. This may be a way of beginning to talk about the enormous social and political costs that will ensue with this continued global crisis. If history and the mismatch between commentary and reality are any guide then the conditions will continue get extremely difficult even as policymakers and the commentariat refuse to discuss the truth or the implications of the situation. There's a good chance that things will get a lot worse and that as John Gray has said a new kind of Gresham's law is in order in which the socially responsible varieties of capitalism will be pushed out by a "race to the bottom" in which "more humane capitalist economies are compelled to deregulate and trim back taxes and welfare provisions." (John Gray. False Dawn, page 218, 1998). That last sentence sounds funny because most countries have already reached the limits of deregulation and of incentivizing anemic capitalism through tax measure. We have only welfare provisions to lose. With that fact looming, people may more and more be pushed to the edge, and at the edge, with less to lose, and with less of a stake they may be less inclined to accept the official views and begin to seek arrangements, collectives, and understandings of of their own. Until such time as people are pushed the edge and as long as the status quo can at least maintain even some appearance of stability, then I would suspect that many people will continue to seek reassurance rather than understanding from commentary. There is however enough discontent with the status quo for dissent to continue to grow and garner support. And uncertainty is evident in the core and not just the periphery. This may be a very propitious time for engineering of what Kenneth Burke called "the shift in allegiance to the symbols of authority." In his still relevant book of 1937 he defined the term that he calls "symbols of authority": he calls it a 'vague term which mashes together attitudes toward rulers, courts, parliaments, laws, educators, constabulary, and more slogans linked to such. It is fundamentally connected with property relations." Kenneth Burke discusses also "how allegiance and obedience to the structures of authority is natural." "One owns his social structure insofar as one can subscribe to it wholeheartedly feeling the reasonableness of its arrangements, and by being spared the need of segregational attitudes. Insofar as such allegiances are frustrated, both the materially and spiritually dispossessed must suffer. We may not be in the mood to pity the losses of those who are not dispossessed materially; but it would be poor gauging for critic not take them into account in considering historical processes. Such spiritual dispossession explains why so many men with the material stake in feudalism could take a sympathetic interest in the revolutionary writings of the encyclopedists. It even explains why Marx, when given a fairly sufficient income from Engel's cotton mills, could nonetheless persist as a renegade. And over-stressing a material possession alone may lead one to alienate men who may be his allies in the gigantic task of engineering shift in allegiance to the symbols of authority. In fact, the peripheral class (the spiritually alienated but still materially rewarded) can contribute insight of the sort to which the holy dispossessed are blinded. To the holy dispossessed, the matter may look to simple, thereby inducing them to make an oversimplified drawing of alignments. And in such oversimplification, they not only organize themselves; they also, by antithesis, organize the enemy â forcing into the enemy camp many who might otherwise have been with them. The issues are aggravated by the negativistic processes we have discussed elsewhere, in connection with the problem of authority and its rejection." I also found Brian's discussions about of both the apparatus and and of profane communication helpful. The apparatus is an excellent way to begin to think about the ways in which the social order in oligopoly capitalism is controlled and channeled through a kind cybernetic normalization. And profane communication is an excellent term for the kind of creative thinking and writing that are necessary to anyone who would seek freedom, clarity, and new alignments. Brian captured something of the casino of the public markets in finance. If we add to that casino, the socialized normalization of the system by a demoralized and shame-faced infrastructure that is not free but that cannot openly declare itself as planned, do we get something of an understanding of the structural and moral crisis of capitalism? # distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a moderated mailing list for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: http://mx.kein.org/mailman/listinfo/nettime-l # archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: nettime@kein.org