t byfield on Fri, 24 Sep 1999 18:06:08 +0200 (CEST) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
<nettime> (fwd) Intellectual Property Rights in Knowledge-Based Economy |
----- Forwarded Date: Thu, 23 Sep 1999 20:09:22 -0400 From: James Love <love@cptech.org> To: INFO-POLICY-NOTES <info-policy-notes@essential.org> Subject: NA project on: Intellectual Property Rights in a Knowledge-Based Economy INFO-POLICY-NOTES (list management at http://www.cptech.org/lists.html) The following is a description of a project on Intellectual Property Rights in a Knowledge-Based Economy, by the National Academies' Board of Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP). The project has apparently already lead to some evaluations of intellectual property issues by the Clinton Administration. It proposes an important and far reaching empirical review of core issues in national policy regarding intellectual property policy. Jamie Love <love@cptech.org> http://www4.nas.edu/pd/step.nsf/8525648b0070c170852562cb0073ff22/371702b9c0c250a38525674d0061f3a6 BOARD ON SCIENCE, TECHNOLOGY, AND ECONOMIC POLICY Intellectual Property Rights in a Knowledge-Based Economy Summary of Project Background Policy Context Analytical Context Summary In advanced industrial economies where, increasingly, intellectual assets are the principal source of value, productivity, and growth, strong intellectual property rights (IPRs)-conferred by patents, copyrights, and penalties for misappropriation of trade secrets-are an important inducement to invention and investment. For this reason, the extension and strengthening of IPRs in the United States and elsewhere in the past 25 years were appropriate and probably necessary. It may be that in some respects those processes should proceed further. On the other hand, there is growing friction over the assertion and exercise of some IPRs and claims that in some circumstances they may be discouraging research, its communication, and use. The question arises whether in some respects IPR strengthening and extension have proceeded too far. To provide answers to guide IPR policy over the next decade and beyond, the Science, Technology and Economic Policy Board (STEP) of the National Research Council (NRC) proposes to undertake a 33-month project in two phases. In the first 15 months, the Board will organize a major conference to review the purposes of the IPR legal framework and assess how well those purposes are being served. The Board will identify whether there are now or emerging problems of inadequate or over-protection of IPRs that need attention. In a second phase of approximately 18 months the Board will form an expert committee to analyze and propose solutions to particular issues selected from the earlier deliberations. Background Policy Context. For purposes of this proposal, intellectual property rights (IPRs) refer to patents (governed by federal law and administration), copyrights (governed by federal law and administration since 1976), and trade secrets or know-how (governed by state law until 1996). It does not include trademarks and tradenames. From about mid-1800s to the mid-1970s, federal government IPR policies were relatively stable and politically unimportant. In the past 20 years, beginning with the Copyright Act of 1976, federal legislative and diplomatic activities have increased and several notable judicial decisions have been rendered, most of them in the direction of increasing the scope and private value (sometimes called the "strength") of IPRs: - the 1976 Copyright Act leading to copyrights for computer software; - the 1980 Bayh-Dole Act, enabling small business, university, and other nonprofit federal contractors and grantees to obtain exclusive rights to their inventions (gradually extended to most contractors); - the Supreme Court's 1980 decision in Diamond v. Chakrabarty, establishing the patentability of genetically engineered organisms; - the creation in 1982 of the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals (FCCA), frequently perceived as strengthening the position of patent holders in infringement litigation; - the Semiconductor Chip Protection Act of 1984, creating a new federally enforceable right to prevent copying of semiconductor designs; - the 1984 Hatch-Waxman Act extending the patent terms on regulated pharmaceuticals; - the 1988 Process Patent Amendments Act, blocking the import to the United States of foreign products produced by methods infringing U.S. process patents; - the 1994 Uruguay Round Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Protection (TRIPS) and various bilateral agreements, ostensibly strengthening foreign IPR protection and harmonizing national standards; - the Economic Espionage Act of 1996 creating, for the first time, federal criminal and civil penalties for theft of trade secrets by foreign agents or U.S. citizens; - the Digital Millennium Copyright Act of 1998; and - the 1998 FCCA decision upholding the patentability of business application software patents. Not all legislative activity resulted in greater IPR protection. The term of a patent was changed so that in some instances the patent has a shorter or less predictable term and therefore a lesser expected value. Judicial decisions, too, sometimes limited the scope of protection. The net effect of the international "harmonization" efforts is unclear. Although many groups supported the principal policy changes on the basis that they increased research incentives, others have expressed concern that in some circumstances the assertion and exercise of IPRs are discouraging or may discourage research, its communication, and its commercial use. These issues can be categorized by their potential effects: 1) on the performance and communication of academic research - concern that an international agreement favored by the European Union and the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) to extend copyrights to scientific databases will inhibit research; - concern that expressed gene sequence (EST) and other biological material patents will make it prohibitively complicated and expensive to conduct research using these tools or, alternatively, expose research investigators to infringement suits; - concern that allowing federal grantees to obtain patents has altered their incentives to conduct basic versus applied research; - concern that universities', researchers', and sponsoring companies' financial interests in exploiting academic results (by IPRs and otherwise) are inhibiting open, timely scientific communication; and - concern that universities' and potential industry research sponsors' inability to resolve differences over IPRs will discourage corporate support of academic research. 2) on personnel mobility and informal technical communication between rival companies - concern that enforcement of new federal trade secrecy laws, providing civil and criminal penalties for misappropriation, will have a chilling effect on mobility and informal know-how trading among firms. 3) on industry investment in R&D and innovation, both radical and incremental, initial and subsequent innovation - concern about the uncertainty of the scope of IPRs; - concern that slow and secret patent administration processes reduce R&D incentives; - concern about high litigation uncertainties and costs, both financially and in terms of the time of scientists, engineers, and managers; and - concern about licensing terms barring probing the intellectual content of software or genomic material and making modifications and improvements (so-called "decompilation") 4) on industry competition and structure - concern about the use of patent portfolios to block competitors' entry or discourage related research; and - concern about the penalties for initial innovators (e.g., business software developers) when IPR protection shifts from trade secrecy to patents. Finally, while the U.S. policy thrust remains in the direction of strengthening and extending IPRs and harmonizing national IPR regimes at a high level of protection, it is also true that there are unresolved and highly contentious policy issues. For example, omnibus patent legislation remains stalemated in Congress by disputes over provisions establishing the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office as an independent corporation, requiring publication of patent applications after 18 months, establishing a prior use defense to allegations of infringement, and broadening the participation of third parties in patent reexamination proceedings. Further, reconciliation of the U.S. first to invent patent principal with the first to file principal predominant abroad is not on the table for discussion because it would be too controversial, raising basic questions about what patent law should encourage. Analytical Context. It is well known that the use of, reliance upon, and effects of intellectual property rights protections vary across industries and technologies, but until recently there has been remarkably little empirical research, other than opinion survey research, documenting these differences. This is beginning to change, and the effects of some of the policy changes in the 1980s and 1990s are beginning to be investigated. For example, the creation of the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals was associated with an increase in patenting that continues and in recent years has accelerated. This suggests that the effort to strengthen patent rights has indeed increased their importance and may have contributed to the growth of industrial R&D funding. On the other hand, these trends contrast with recent survey evidence suggesting that U.S. manufacturing firms in most industries rely more heavily on trade secrecy, lead time, and technological protections (e.g., encryption) to recoup their R&D investments than they do on legal mechanisms such as patents and that, if anything, the effectiveness of patents as a means of appropriating R&D returns has declined since the early 1980s. There is very little evidence about the importance of patents as a means of disseminating technical information, although this is one of the principal rationales for the patent system and appears to be an important function of patents in Japan. In short, the effects of IPR changes on innovation and technical advance are highly uncertain -- with respect to either the incentive provided to the innovator to capture the benefits of his invention, investment, and effort or the encouragement to the innovator to provide the information to others who might improve upon it. The project will attempt to synthesize the results of recent research and resolve differences or propose additional research to help resolve the differences in findings. >From both the policy and analytical points of view, a broad reassessment of IPR policies is therefore very timely. What have been the costs and benefits of the actions taken in the last several years? The unintended as well intended consequences? What should be the direction of IPR policies in the next decade of two decades? The Academy has addressed some of these issues but mainly from two points of view-the impact of expanding IPRs on university research and the technological aspects of protecting information on the Internet. -- James Love, Director, Consumer Project on Technology I can be reached at love@cptech.org, by telephone 202.387.8030, by fax at 202.234.5176. CPT web page is http://www.cptech.org ----- Backwarded # distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a moderated mailing list for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: majordomo@bbs.thing.net and "info nettime-l" in the msg body # archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: nettime@bbs.thing.net